Briefs.png

Financing Government Debt

The Medium Term Budget Policy Statement, tabled in Parliament on 28 October 2020, projects that the government will need to issue above 50% more short-term and long-term domestic debt in 2020/21 than in 2019/20. In this Brief Charles Simkins considers if the targets can be met and what the macroeconomic implications of doing so would be.
Financing Government Debt

You mean to tell me that the success of the program and my reelection hinges on the Federal Reserve and a bunch of fucking bond traders? - Bill Clinton, 1993

The only opposition to Erdogan left is the lira.


- Turkish joke, 2018

Introduction

The Medium Term Budget Policy Statement, tabled in Parliament on 28 October 2020, projects that the government will need to issue above 50% more short-term and long-term domestic debt in 2020/21 than in 2019/20. This elevated level will persist for two more years. And, as the Minister of Finance pointed out, the risks to this baseline projection are to the downside.

Can the target be met? And what are the macroeconomic implications of doing so?

The baseline projection and the risks

Table 1

Table 1 sets out the baseline projection.

Gross borrowing requirement

2019/20

 2020/21

 2021/22

 2022/23

 2023/24

Financing (R billion)

         

Net domestic short term loans

36.1

143.0

67.0

71.0

62.0

Domestic long term loans

305.4

462.5

472.2

500.8

436.8

Foreign loans

76.1

121.4

49.4

49.3

66.6

Change in cash and other balances

-1.8

47.8

14.3

16.1

27.8

 

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.0

Total

415.8

774.7

602.9

637.2

593.2

Annexure A to the Medium Term Budget Budget Policy Statement sets out the risks to this projection. They are:

  1. The possibility that the economic recovery will not be strong enough to allow for the full withdrawal of temporary support under the COVID-19 fiscal support measures, particularly if there is a second wave of the epidemic.
  2. A high likelihood of further rating agency downgrades, which would put upward pressure on funding costs.
  3. A further reduction in non-resident holdings of domestic debt.
  4. A depreciation of the rand, increasing the rand value of foreign debt service payments.
  5. Subnational government risks in the form of medico-legal claims, unpaid provincial invoices and the poor financial situation of municipalities.
  6. Contingent liabilities: By 2022/23, contingent liabilities are expected to exceed R1 trillion. These liabilities consist of government guarantees to state-owned companies, the Renewable Energy Independent Power Producer Programme, public-private partnerships (PPPs), and obligations to the Road Accident Fund and other social security funds.
  7. Bailouts for state owned enterprises, including the Airports Company of South Africa, Denel, Eskom, Land Bank, the Post Office, the Road Accident Fund and the South African National Road Agency Limited.
  8. Inability of the state to hold the line on public sector wages.. Both the upcoming decision on the final year of the current wage agreement and the upcoming wage talks pose significant risks to the expenditure ceiling.

The National Treasury has quantified some, but not all, of the effects of these risks on gross loan debt in 2020/21.

Table 2

Impact of risks on gross loan debt in 2020/21

 
 

R billion

Treasury estimates

 

10% increase in interest rates

23.5

10% depreciation in the Rand against the dollar

49.6

10% increase in the inflation rate

3.1

Further estimates

 

Additional COVID support

5.0

Additional SOE bailouts

7.5

5% increase in public sector wages

32.0

The public wage sector bill impact has the potential to snowball in succeeding years and pressures for SOE bailouts may continue to climb.

The financing problem

Here there are three critically important issues:

1. Foreign sentiment. South African government debt depends on foreign sentiment in two ways: the willingness of non-residents to hold domestic bonds and their willingness to hold bonds denominated in foreign currencies. The importance of non-resident holdings of domestic bonds is illustrated in Figure 1.

051120.png

In addition, the rand value of foreign debt was R 350.0 billion in June 2020, 11.5% of all government debt. Adverse moves in foreign sentiment will depreciate the rand, increase the debt service costs of foreign loans and throw more of the financing burden on domestic lenders. All foreign lenders and investors are looking for the same two things: a reduction in the probability of debt default and a credible path to higher growth.

2. Domestic absorption capacity. The decrease in the proportion of domestic debt has been compensated for mainly by an increase in the proportion held by banks and, to a lesser extent, by other financial institutions, including unit trusts and finance companies. The MTBPS Annexure A points out that 15.3% of total banking assets are government bonds now, up from 7.7% a decade ago. If adverse moves in foreign sentiment develop, questions will arise about the willingness of banks and other financial institutions to shoulder the increased financing burden, leading to a drop in the bid to cover ratio (the ratio of all bids for government bonds to bonds allocated in auctions) leading to upward pressure on interest rates.

3. The Reserve Bank. Reserve Bank policy is not to intervene by influencing the market rate of interest on government debt, but to act as purchaser of last resort in the event that spikes in the interest rates arise from disorderly market conditions. Disorder would arise in the event of a much reduced willingness to bid from other purchasers. In making emergency purchases, the Reserve Bank would increase the stock of money with potentially inflationary consequences, with implications for monetary policy. It would be an induced form of quantitative easing.

Conclusion

Financing of baseline government debt will be tricky enough. Forced additions to it will lead to mutually reinforcing higher than expected rand depreciation, a higher government debt yield curve, putting upward pressure on debt service costs, and higher inflation. This in turn will increase interest rates, choking off the investment on which the government is relying for improved growth. Avoiding these developments will require both good luck and a steely determination by the government to stick to its MTBPS commitments. The prospects for that determination will be discussed in a later brief.

Charles Simkins
Head of Research
charles@hsf.org.za